A BIBLIOGRAPHICAL NOTE ON TRADE IN SERVICES: CONCEPTS AND LIBERALIZATION PRINCIPLES
Source: Economic Commission for Latin America and the
Caribbean
Note
(Continued)
III. BASIC PRINCIPLES FOR
LIBERALIZATION |
The extent to which the commitments actually provide a
rollback of restrictions can only be determined by an analysis of the legislative changes
introduced by members to implement their concessions.
The term, transparency, stands for the proposition that "the marking
of legislation, including regulations, rules and all subordinate legislation, and
including the detail of special arrangements for the benefit of a particular corporation
or class of corporation, should be a public process." One issue on which at least all
the market-economy country regimes ought to be able to agree, and with regard to all
service industry, is that laws and regulations should be notified to trading partners and
should be administered under public procedures, that rules should be published and
therefore that the scope for discrimination against legitimate foreign traders can be
reduced. Article X of the GATT, for instance, sets out requirements regarding the
"Publication and Administration of Trade Regulations". Also, many important
sections of the various Tokyo Round codes on procurement, technical standards,
subsidy-countervailing measures and on anti-dumping actions are addressed to
"transparency". Article III of the GATS on Transparency requires all Members to
establish enquiry points to provide specific information concerning any laws, regulations,
and administrative practices respecting services covered by the Agreement. |
For detailed historical analysis of the concept of transparency, see Grey,
op.cit., pp.130-133
Grey, pp.120-121. |
III. BASIC PRINCIPLES FOR
LIBERALIZATION |
2. DISCRIMINATION
a) Reciprocity
Though the articles of GATT do not define reciprocity or specify how
reciprocal negotiations may be arranged, the Preamble of GATT refers to "entering
reciprocal and mutually advantageous arrangements directed to the substantial reduction of
tariffs and other barriers to trade". However, that:
"Reciprocity, the notion that there has to be some broadly equal and
specific, identifiable concession from the foreign country obtaining the benefit of a
particular concession...and, carried to the extreme, from each separate foreign country
obtaining that benefit, is a concept with a long and controversial history. In its extreme
and most precise form, it is obviously much the same, in relation to trade in goods, as,
conditional - MFN treatment. But at different times, for different countries and in
various political contexts, the term, reciprocity - has had different meanings." The
concept is hence used in negotiations, not in economics. Messerlin (1990, p. 142) defines
reciprocity as "the threshold of mutual concessions that trade partners consider
satisfactory enough to sign a trade agreement". From a pure mercantilist point of
view, as Dell (1986) writes, "What it means is obscure and subjective and, in the
end, may be determined simply by what is politically acceptable", and "There is
free trade and there is reciprocity". Similarly, Winters (1987, p.45) argues that
"Reciprocity in trade negotiations comes in many disguises, ranging from the simple
bilateral swapping of tariff reductions, through multilateral reciprocity, to qualitative
reciprocity in which mutual concessions are made in the design of agenda or of codes of
practice."
In cross-border services, national treatment links reciprocity to host
country rules, as it does in trade in goods. However, the fact that suppliers of services
are subject to host country rules does not necessarily lead to an acceptable bargain, when
producers in the most liberal country are seen as disadvantaged in comparison with the
counterparts in the less liberal country. Thus, the "comparable competitive
opportunities" concept makes the assessment of reciprocity more complex because it
compares host and home country rules (Messerlin, 1990, p.142). Under these circumstances,
either the rule of the most regulated home country, the rule of the most liberal country,
or somewhere in between the two extremes could be accepted as the international standard
for reciprocity. |
For the concept of reciprocity, see: Grey, op.cit., Chapter 6, pp.
97-119; Patrick A. Messerlin, "The European Community" in World Bank and UNCTC,
pp.132-149, The Uruguay Round, Services in the World Economy, op.cit.;
Murray Gibbs and Michiko Hayashi "Sectoral issues and the multilateral framework for
trade in services: an overview", Trade in Services: Sectoral Issues, UNCTAD,
(UNCTAD/ITP/26) Geneva, 1989; Alan Winters, "Reciprocity", in J. Michael Finger
and Andrzej Olechowski eds., The Uruguay Round: A Handbook for the Multilateral Trade
Negotiations, The World Bank, Washington D.C. 1987; Edmund Dell, "Of Free Trade
and Reciprocity", The World Economy, 9, June, 1986, pp. 125-40; William R.
Cline, "Reciprocity: A New Approach to World Trade Policy", in W. R. Cline ed., Trade
Policy in the 1980s, Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., 1983.
Messerlin, op.cit.. |
III. BASIC PRINCIPLES FOR
LIBERALIZATION |
This wide range of options makes trade
negotiations difficult. It is to be noted that reciprocity is a conflict of interests not
only between trading partners but also within each domestic industry of the two trading
partners. In trade in services, the application of multilateral reciprocity is more
complex, due to the difficulty of applying a mechanism affecting all service sectors,
comparable to an across-the-board tariff reduction and the need to address the different
modes of supply.
The term "relative reciprocity" has emerged in the negotiations
as a means of calibrating developing country concessions in line with their development
needs. This approach appears somewhat analogous to the so-called
"non-reciprocity" provision contained in Part IV of GATT (Article XXXVI:8) which
states that "the developed contracting parties do not expect reciprocity for
commitments made by them in trade negotiations to reduce or remove tariffs and other
barriers to the trade of less developed countries." Relative reciprocity appears to
imply that concessions granted by developing countries should be matched by much more
substantial liberalization by developed countries. In contrast to the case of trade in
goods, in which developing countries are the demandeurs, seeking access to markets for
specific products, in trade in services, it is primarily the developed countries which are
seeking access commitments in developing country markets. "The problem in the
negotiation on trade in services is not the ability of developing countries to grant
reciprocity, it is rather how developing countries will obtain reciprocity from developed
countries in respect of any concessions they might agree to make." (Gibbs and
Hayashi, 1989, p. 43).
b) Partial liberalization (regional)
Agreements to liberalize international transactions in trade on a
regional basis have been of recent vintage. Examples include the Canada-United States Free
Trade Agreement (FTA), the Australia-New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement
(ANZCERTA), the European Community's Single Market (EC-92), and NAFTA. In conjunction to
the GATS, Hoekman and Sauvé (1994) provide a detailed comparative analysis on services,
especially from the viewpoints of modalities and instruments of liberalization, sectoral
coverage, disciplines on related government policies, enforcement and dispute settlement,
rules of origin and safeguards. |
Gibbs and Hayashi, op.cit..
Reference to regional integration in the context of the GATS is found in:
Bernard Hoekman and Pierre Sauvé, Liberalizing Trade in Services, World Bank
Discussion Paper No. 243, Washington D.C., 1994: Handbook, op.cit., as well
as UNCTAD (1994, pp. 157-158), also refer to regional integration in the context of the
GATS. Richard, Snape, "History and Economics of GATT's Article XXIV," in Kym
Anderson and Richard Blackhurst eds., Regional Integration and the Global Trading
System, London, harvester-Wheatsheaf, 1993; Frieder Roessler, "The Relationship
Between Regional Integration Agreements and the Multilateral Trade Order", in Kym
Anderson and Richard Blackhurst eds., Regional Integration and the Global Trading
System, London, harvester-Wheatsheaf, 1993. |
III. BASIC PRINCIPLES FOR
LIBERALIZATION |
Article XXIV of GATT and Article V of GATS are the
provisions covering economic integration, requiring arrangements to have "substantial
sectoral coverage" and to "provide for the absence or elimination of
substantially all discrimination" between the parties. Yet, both contain provisions
which allow for the formation of agreements that do not comply with multilateral
disciplines. In the former, with a two-thirds majority GATT members may approve a proposed
regional trade agreement that does not fully comply with Article XXIV, provided that such
proposals lead to the formation of a customs union or free trade area in the sense of
Article XXIV. Similarly, Articles V:2 and V.3(a) of the GATS respectively allow for
consideration to be given to the relationship between a particular regional agreement and
the wider process of economic integration among member countries, and give developing
countries flexibility regarding the realization of the internal liberalization
requirements (Art. V:1). Both agreements impose conditions that external barriers may not
be increased unless affected parties are compensated, and internal (preferential)
liberalization must have substantial sectoral coverage. In those cases where there remains
ambiguity with respect to the standstill-cum-substantial sectoral coverage, Article V:2 of
GATS allows that a regional agreement should be accepted insofar as it is part of a wider
process of economic integration or trade liberalization among the member countries.
(Hoekman and Sauvé, 1994, p. 62).
c) Developing country-specific provisions
Article XVIII of GATT of 1947, entitled "Government Assistance to
Economic Development" allowed developing countries to impose quantitative and other
restrictions in order to protect infant industries and (after amendment in 1955) to combat
payments imbalances. Part IV of GATT relieved developing countries from the obligation to
make reciprocal concessions in order to benefit on a MFN basis from the tariff and other
concessions made by other GATT members. In addition, the Decision of the Contracting
Parties of 28 November 1979 on Differential and More Favorable Treatment, Reciprocity, and
Fuller Participation of Developing Countries stated:
"Notwithstanding the provisions of article I of the General
Agreement, contracting parties may accord differential and more favourable treatment to
developing countries, without according such treatment to other contracting parties"
(GATT, 1979, pp.5-7). |
A selective bibliographic list of a detailed
treatment on services includes:with respect to the European Community, see Brian Hindley,
"Trade in services with the European Community", in Herbert Giersch, ed., Free
Trade in the World Economy, Tubingen, J.C.B., Mohr, 1987 and Patrick Messerlin,
"The European Community", in the World Bank and UNCTC, op.cit., pp.
132-149; with respect to the USA-Canada agreement, Jeffrey Schott and Murray Smith,
"Services and Investment", in J. Schott and M. Smith, eds., The Canada-US
Free Trade Agreement: The Global Impact, Washington D.C., Institute for International
Economics, 1988; for NAFTA, see Gary Clyde Hubbauer and Jeffrey J. Schott, NAFTA: An
Assessment, Washington D.C., Institute for International Economics, 1993; and Alberto
Musalem, Dimitri Vittas and Asli Dermirguc-Kunt, "North American Free Trade
Agreement: Issues on Trade in Financial Services for Mexico", Policy Research Working
Paper No. 1153, Washington D.C., The World Bank, 1993. Regarding the ANZCERTA, Richard
Snape, "A free trade agreement with Australia", in J. Schott, ed., Free Trade
Areas and U.S. Trade Policy, Washington D.C., Institute for International Economics,
1989, pp. 167-196.
For a more detailed discussion, see UNCTAD and World Bank, Handbook,
op.cit. (1994, pp.144-146). UNCTAD, The Outcome of the Uruguay Round: An Initial
Assessment. Supporting Papers to the Trade and Development Report 1994, New York,
(Sales No.: E.94.II.D28), 1994, pp. 155-157. UNCTAD, The Outcome of the Uruguay Round:
An Initial Assessment, Supporting Papers to the Trade and Development Report, 1994,
Annex 1 to Chapter 1, pp. 17-27, New York, 1994; Brian Hindley, "Different and more
favorable treatment -- and graduation", in J. Michael Finger and Andrzej Olechowski
eds, The Uruguay Round: A Handbook for the Multilateral Trade Negotiations, World
Bank, Washington D.C., 1987; Martin Wolf, "Differential and More Favorable Treatment
of Developing Countries and the International Trading System", The World Bank
Economic Review, Vol. 1, No.4, pp. 647-668; GATT Descripción de las disposiciones
relativas a los países en desarrollo contenidas en los acuerdos, instrumentos jurídicos
y decisiones ministeriales de la Ronda Uruguay, |
III. BASIC PRINCIPLES FOR
LIBERALIZATION |
This article had four aspects: i) special and different (S
& D) treatment in the context of codes on non-tariff barriers; ii) exemption from the
requirement of Article XXIV, mentioned above; iii) eligibility under the GSP for lower
rates of duty on their exports to developed countries than apply to similar exports from
other developed countries; and iv) particularly special treatment for least developed
countries. The narrowest definition of "differential and more favorable
treatment" would look only at item i) above. A somewhat broader definition would
include all the four enumerated exceptions (Wolf, p. 649).
The Tokyo Round was a culminating point in the process of creating
consensus in favor of S & D treatment. The so-called Enabling Clause provided a legal
basis for the GSP, but did not make it obligatory. The codification of S & D treatment
resulted in the explicit introduction of the concept of graduation into the Enabling
Clause, stating that it should be available only according to need and for a limited time
period. Without a clear criterion for classifying a country as developing and for
graduation, in practice developed countries 'graduated' developing ones unilaterally from
GSP eligibility. The result of the Uruguay Round has reduced the S & D concept
further: with minor exceptions, it is addressed in terms of longer periods of adjustment
for developing countries to international norms that are applicable to all countries
(Agosin, Tussie and Crespi, 1994).
The GATS does not contain provisions similar to Part IV of the GATT on
more favorable treatment of developing countries (S & D treatment), or to the
(unilateral) arrangements for tariff preferences that exist for merchandize trade flows
(e.g., GSP). Instead, all provisions relating to economic development are considered
integral elements of the GATS.
Although Article XIX allows developing countries to offer fewer specific
commitments than industrialized countries, this is either a right nor obligation. No
developing country (including least developing ones) has been allowed to become a Member
of the GATS without scheduling at least one service sector. Other provisions addressing
developing country concerns include Article IV (Increasing Participation of Developing
Countries), III (Transparency), V (Economic Integration), XV (Subsidies), and XXV
(technical cooperation). Article IV and XXV are the only two provisions that deal
exclusively with developing countries. |
Nota de la Secretaría,
(COM.TD/W/510), November, 1994; GATT, Descripción de las disposiciones relativas a los
países menos adelantados contenidas en los acuerdos, instrumentos jurídicos y
decisiones ministeriales de la Ronda Uruguay, (COM/TD/LLDC/W/54), November, 1994;
Manuel Agosin, Diana Tussie and Gustavo Crespi, Developing Countries and the Uruguay
Round: An Evaluation and Issues for the Future, Documento de Trabajo No. 129,
Departamento de Economía, Universidad de Chile, October, 1994.
Agosín, Tussie and Crespi, op.cit.. |
III. BASIC PRINCIPLES FOR
LIBERALIZATION |
Article IV states that increasing the participation of
developing countries in world trade in services is to be facilitated through negotiated
specific commitments relating to : i) access to technology on a commercial basis;
ii) the improvement of access to distribution channels and information networks; and iii)
the liberalization of market access in sectors of export interest to them. As such, this
Article does not exempt developing countries from any obligations of the agreement. On
transparency, industrialized countries are to establish contract points to facilitate the
access of developing country service suppliers to information relating to: i) the
commercial and technical aspects of specific services; ii) requirements for registration,
recognition, and obtaining of professional qualifications; and iii) the availability of
services technology. Article XV recognizes the role of subsidies in development programs
of developing countries, though the GATS disciplines for subsidies are yet to be drafted.
Moreover, the telecommunications annex contains a separate Article on technical
cooperation in this industry. |
|
IV. MEASURES WHICH AFFECT ACCESS TO
THE SERVICES MARKET |
There is a wide variety of policy instruments
to restrict access to markets. Five broad categories of instruments can be distinguished
as impediments to trade in services (Hoekman, 1994,p.7): i) measures that are
quantity-based (i.e., that explicitly restrict the volume or value of transactions); ii)
those that are price-based, involving the imposition of a monetary fee (tax) on foreign
suppliers who desire to access to a market; iii) those that require physical or corporate
presence in market; iv) those relating to standards, certification requirements and
industry-specific regulations; and v) measures relating to government procurement and
subsidization, where discriminaiton tends to be the rule rather than the exception.
a) Non-discriminatory Quantitative Measures
Among those mentioned, the most important in the services context are
quantitative restrictions and standards. Quantitative restrictions may limit the quantity
and/or value of imports of specific products for a given time period; restrict the number
and/or market share of foreign service providers allowed to establish; or ration the
amount of foreign exchange that may be used to import services. Such discriminatory
quantitative measures are often complemented by non-discriminatory ones (i.e., measures
that apply generally regardless of the nationality or origin of service providers). The
latter are called "quantitative restrictions" in the NAFTA (Hoekman and Sauvé,
1994, p.17). These usually consist of limitations on the number of firms allowed to
contest a market, or on the nature of their operations. Frequently, this involves either a
monopoly (e.g., basic telecomunications services) or oligopolistic market structures
(e.g., banking or self-regulating professional services) (Hoekman and Sauvé, 1994, p.7).
b) Price-based Measures
Though import tariffs and taxes rarely impede trade in services, when
found, they often take the form of discriminatory user charges, such as, for instance,
port taxes and airline landing fees. Tariffs are, however, potentially important barriers
to trade in servicies either embodied in goods (e.g., films, television programs and
computer software on disk or tape) or for goods that are necessary inputs into the
production of servicies (e.g., computers and telecommunications equipment). More common
are price controls. |
On the issue of market access from the
viewpoint of services, consult, Bernard Hoekman, "Market Access Through Multilateral
Agreement: From Goods to Services", The World Economy, Vol.15, No.6,
pp.707-727. A series of detailed sectoral studies on market access are provided in: A
Typology of Barriers to Trade in Services, Prepared by Peat Marwick, Michell &
Co., July, 1986; and UNCTAD, Trade in Services: Sectoral Issues, op.cit..
For a review on quatitative restrictions, see: Handbook, op.cit.,
p.57 and pp.115-119; Bernard Hoekman and Pierre Sauvé, Liberalizing Trade in Services,
op.cit..
Handbook, 1994, op.cit., pp. 119-121. |
IV. MEASURES WHICH AFFECT ACCESS TO
THE SERVICES MARKET |
These measures might consist either of price-setting by
government agencies (e.g., imposition of minimum or maximum prices, enforcement of uniform
pricing) and/or price monitoring and approval procedures. Often being exercised together
with capacity or quantitative restrictions, they intend to ensure that prices are not set
either market-clearing levels or at the monopoly level. Examples of service industries
suject to price controls include air transportation, financial services and
telecommunications.
c) Right of Establishment and Market Presence
The term, establishment, normally connotates "the relatively
lengthy residence of an alien or a foreign-controlled firm in the territory for the
purpose of exercising some activity." (UNCTC, 1990, p.7). In tax treaties,
"permanent establishment" refers to the setting up of a local operation, of a
commercial or other character. In the context of Treaties of Friendship, Commerce and
Navigation, the term is "normally applied in reffering to some of the rights provided
therein."(UNCTC, 1990, p.7). Therefore, the "right" or "freedom"
of establishment covers the right of an alien or a foreign-controlled enterprise: i) to
enter the territory of the State concerned; ii) to reside there; iii) to set up and manage
companies; iv) to pursue the economic and other activities expressly listed in the
agreement; and v) sometimes subject to qualifications, to acquire, own and use property in
that State." Though not necessarily connected with investment, the term is especially
associated with it (UNCTC, 1990, p.7).
In the definition of Grey (1989, p.121), "The right of establishment
is the right of a foreign controlled entity to create a facility in the domestic
jurisdiction, in conformity with the licensing procedures and requirements as to
capitalization etc. which apply to demestically-organized entities". In this sense,
an unequivocal right of establishment would carry with it national treatment for such
purposes. In practice, however, rights of establishment are often not absolute rights, but
are severely conditioned or, for certain industries, non-existent. For example,
application of the principle of national treatment can significantly limit the exercise of
that right (Hindley, 1990, p.15).
The notion of "commercial presence" has been used to account for
various degrees of permanent activity of a foreign firm within the importing country.
Though in some cases it may resemble the types of activity associated with the export of
goods, such presence often goes beyond it becuase a flow of production factors is often
invovled. In fact, the degree of presence varies, ranging from a local representative, a
plant for assembly of products whose components are all imported, a full local production
by foreign-controlled firms. |
Bernard Hoekman and Pierre Sauvé, Liberalizing Trade in Services,
World Bank Discussion Paper No. 243, Washington D.C., 1994. Rodney de C. Grey, Concepts
of Trade Diplomacy and Trade in Services, Thames Essay No.56, Trade Policy Research
Centre, London. Bian Hindley, "Principles in Factor-related Trade in Services"
in World Bank and UNCTC, The Uruguay Round, Services in the World Economy,
Washington, D.C. and New York, 1990.UNCTC, Key Concepts in International Investment
Arrangements and Their Relevance to Negotiations on International Transactions in Services,
UNCTC Current Studies, Series A. No. 13, United Nations, February, 1990, Chapter I. |
IV. MEASURES WHICH AFFECT ACCESS TO
THE SERVICES MARKET |
Therefore, when it assumes the character of
foreign direct investment, "commercial presence" blends into
"establishment". The types of questions concerning foreign direct investment
often relate to capital movements, including exchange control and profit remittances,
transfer of technology, employment, regulation of the professionals, double taxation, etc.
Many service markets are only contestable by establishing a physical
presence. Considerations relating to consumer protection, prudential supervision and
regulatory oversight often induce governments to require establishment by foreign
providers (e.g., financial or professional services. By contrast, drawing from the FTA,
the NAFTA provides for an explicit right of non-establishment by outlawing all future
measures the local presence of firms or service providers (i.e., residency requirements
for professionals) as a pre-condition for the delivery of a service (Hoekman and Sauvé,
1994, p.18).
d) Standards, Certification Requirements and Industry-Specific
Regulations
With respect to certification requirements, there are fudamentally two
different systems. One the one hand, the countries in Western and Eastern Europe, Latin
America, Asia and Africa tend to use a state-regulated system of licensing in which
licenses are obtained upon satisfactory completion of a univeristy or vocational-technical
level course. On the other, Anglo-Saxon countries and those borrowed this approach, tend
to rely on industry-regulated professional licensing systems. Under the latter, the
acquisition of a license is usually contingent upon completion of an appropriate
educational degree, a period of practical training under the supervision of licensed
practitioners, as well as satisfactory completion of licensing examinations administered
by the professional association.
When extending a licence to a foreign professional, the regulatory bodies
of individual host countries may creat a number of limitations, ranging from the
nationality or residency, language profeciency, diploma equivalency, defined locations
permmited for the practice, the scope of services, compulsory membership in a professional
association, etc. |
A concise summary of the issues related to this topic is provided in Handbook,
op.cit., pp.103-114; and Thierry Noyelle, "Business services and the Uruguay
Round negotiations on trade in services", in UNCTAD, Trade in Services: Sectoral
Issues, op.cit., pp.309-363. |
IV. MEASURES WHICH AFFECT ACCESS TO
THE SERVICES MARKET |
e) Government Procurement and Subsidization
Government procurement and sourcing policies often entail preferences
given to domestic over foreign firms in bidding on public-procurement contracts. Examples
of such discriminatory practices, which restrict market access for foreign firms, include
outright prohibitions of foreign sourcing, formal criteria for foreign sourcing to be
permitted (e.g., minimum cost or price differentials, offset or local content
requirements), and informal procedures favoring procurement from domestic firms.
Government procurement tends to be excluded from the scope of most of the
agreements. The procurement disciplines of the FTA applied only to goods, while the GATS
and ANZCERTA do not cover government procurements of services (Hoekman and Sauvé, 1994,
p. 52). Article XIII:1 of GATS on Government Procurement states that " Articles II,
XVI and XVII shall not apply to laws, regulations or requirements governing the
procurement by government agencies of services purchased for governmental purposes and not
with a view to commercial resale or with a view to use in the supply of services for
commercial resale." The question of rules on this matter is left for future
negotiations to be completed two years after the date of entry into force of the Agreement
Establishing the WTO. Given that government contracts are extremely important in certain
sectors (e.g., construction), the absence of provisions could create distortions in trade
in services.
However, the revised Government Procurement Agreement (GPA), Annex 4 of
the Agrement Establishing the WTO, which entered into force in January 1996 but applies
only to signatories, in principle prohibits preferences for domestic firms by imposing
GATT's national treatment and nondiscrimination principles. This way, foreign suppliers
and foreign goods and services should be given no less favorable treatment in government
procurement by the coverved entities than national suppliers and goods and services. The
entities covered by the GPA consist of central government entities (e.g., Ministries),
sub-central entities e.g., Provinces) and all other entities, including public utilities
(Hoekman, 1995, p. 39). The GPA scope was enhanced in the Uruguay Round not only by the
entities covered but also by the inclusion of services and construction contracts.
Procurement of the latter product categories is covered only for listed entities, and then
only for those services that are explicitly listed in annexes to the GPA for each
signatory (Hoekman, 1995, p. 39). |
Bernard Hoekman, Trade Laws and Institutions: Good Practices and the
World Trade Organization, op.cit., pp. 38-39; Bernard Hoekman and Pierre
Sauvé, Liberalizing Trade in Services, World Bank Discussion Paper 243, Washington
D.C., World Bank, 1994, pp.52-53; The Outcome of the Uruguay Round: An Initial
Assessment. Supporting Papers to the Trade and Development Report 1994, New York,
(Sales No.: E.94.II.D28), 1994, pp. 160-161; Handbook, 1994, op.cit.,
pp.121-122. |
IV. MEASURES WHICH AFFECT ACCESS TO THE SERVICES MARKET |
Regarding subsidies destined towards service industries,
none of the agreements examined by Hoekman and Sauvé (1994, p.52) imposes significant
disciplines, with the exception of EC. For instance, Article XV of the GATS on subsidies
states that while Members to the Agreement recognize that in certain circumstances
subsidies may have distortive effects on trade in services, they shall enter into
negotiations with an aim to developing the necessary multilateral disciplines to avoid
such effects. Though the Protocol on services of the ANZCERTA prohibits new exports
subsidies or measures which have a direct distorting effect on trade, it does not address
more general subsidies insofar as they affect services. The FTA and the NAFTA do not
impose disciplines on services-related subsidies. |
Note
This document (DOC.CEPAL/ALCA/GTS/001) was prepared by the International
Trade Unit of the International Trade, Finance and Transport Division, to be presented at
the Second Meeting of the FTAA Working Group on Services, Santiago, December 2-3. It has
not been subjected to editorial revision.
|